mirror of
https://github.com/ilyakooo0/urbit.git
synced 2024-12-14 17:41:33 +03:00
6ac41c17dc
sorry
566 lines
25 KiB
Plaintext
566 lines
25 KiB
Plaintext
---
|
|
title: Network architecture: goals
|
|
sort: 4
|
|
---
|
|
|
|
# Design of a digital republic: part 1, goals
|
|
|
|
Some of us remember when the Internet was a social network.
|
|
Today, the Internet is a modem.
|
|
|
|
It's a wonderful modem. It connects you to all kinds of great
|
|
online services. Some of which are social "networks," but only
|
|
networks in the MBA sense. Really they're social *servers*:
|
|
giant virtual mainframes running one hardcoded program. 1976
|
|
called — it wants its acoustic coupler back.
|
|
|
|
So, you prefer 1996. So, you wish you had your decentralized
|
|
Internet back. So, you don't seem alone in this. So, we know
|
|
one thing: wishing hasn't made it happen.
|
|
|
|
## John Perry Barlow
|
|
|
|
It's interesting to go back and read John Perry Barlow's 1996
|
|
manifesto, the [Cyberspace Declaration of
|
|
Independence](https://projects.eff.org/~barlow/Declaration-Final.html),
|
|
Some parts of the *Declaration* are dated. Many parts seem
|
|
fresh, even urgent.
|
|
|
|
But in 2015, what stands out most about this document is its
|
|
incredible confidence that the Internet is inherently free, and
|
|
easily strong enough to announce and defend its own freedom,
|
|
against "Governments of the Industrial World, you weary giants of
|
|
flesh and steel."
|
|
|
|
Well... hindsight is 20/20. But in hindsight, even in 1996
|
|
things were starting to head south. Usenet — the brain of the
|
|
Internet, when the Internet had a brain — was already
|
|
disintegrating under the barbarian invasions. And where is the
|
|
WELL these days? (John Perry Barlow is probably still on it.)
|
|
|
|
While the Net has certainly scored a point or two against the
|
|
State, the State has scored a lot more points against the Net.
|
|
If the State wants your domain name, it takes it. If that's
|
|
independence, what does utter defeat and submission look like?
|
|
|
|
Worse: whatever state tyranny exists, it's obviously dwarfed by
|
|
the private, free-market, *corporate* tyrannosaurs that stalk the
|
|
cloud today. We can see this clearly by imagining all these
|
|
thunder-lizards were *actually part of the government*. "Private"
|
|
and "public" are just labels, after all.
|
|
|
|
Imagine a world in which LinkedIn, Facebook, Twitter, Apple and
|
|
the NSA were all in one big org chart. Is there anyone, of any
|
|
political stripe, who doesn't find this outcome creepy? It's
|
|
probably going to happen, in fact if not in form. While formal
|
|
nationalization is out of fashion, regulation easily achieves the
|
|
same result, while keeping the sacred words "private enteprise."
|
|
|
|
Reading Barlow's _Declaration_ is a lot like reading the real
|
|
Declaration, in an alternate history where Jefferson lost. In
|
|
2015, do we still believe in these goals? Arguably, we believe
|
|
in them more than ever. We basically live in 1996's nightmare.
|
|
We know exactly what to be afraid of. It's already here.
|
|
|
|
But we've lost the ability to believe we can *achieve* these
|
|
goals. 20 years ago, digital freedom seemed inevitable. Now it
|
|
seems impossible.
|
|
|
|
## Engineering digital freedom
|
|
|
|
Don't panic! This is a simple case of cause and effect. Digital
|
|
freedom isn't inevitable. It's also not impossible. It's quite
|
|
possible. It just requires *actual engineering work*.
|
|
|
|
If you think a result is inevitable, but it's not, you won't do
|
|
the work and you won't get the result. So, let's do the work.
|
|
Dealing is way better than worrying. 1996 worried about the
|
|
problem; 2016 ought to deal with it.
|
|
|
|
A constitution is not a declaration. It's not a list of ideals.
|
|
It's more like a bridge — an actual structure, that fails unless
|
|
it stands up to genuine load. A bridge isn't a bridge unless it
|
|
works. If you want a bridge, you have to build a bridge. It
|
|
doesn't typically happen that you set out to build something
|
|
else, but at the end it turns out you've built a bridge.
|
|
|
|
The designers of the Internet did not, of course, intend to
|
|
implement any of John Perry Barlow's ideals. How close they came
|
|
is in a way remarkable. Perhaps it was possible for the
|
|
designers of the Internet to build a global, decentralized social
|
|
network. They weren't trying to, and they didn't.
|
|
|
|
If we want a decentralized social network, we can't do it without
|
|
rigorous engineering work. And we can't limit our work to the
|
|
world of code. A decentralized network has to work not just
|
|
technically — but politically, economically, and socially.
|
|
|
|
Where do we go from here? How do we get back to 1996? Admit
|
|
we've failed, and try again. How else?
|
|
|
|
## Two axioms
|
|
|
|
It's rarely worth arguing over an ugly truth. Either you know
|
|
it, or you can't be argued into it. Or it's not true. So it's
|
|
better to just give it as an axiom. Two axioms:
|
|
|
|
One: the Internet can't be fixed. We *can't* redecentralize the
|
|
Internet. It has too many accumulated administrative and
|
|
technical misfeatures.
|
|
|
|
Two: there is no practical, completely decentralized network.
|
|
Government is a human invariant, in the digital world as in the
|
|
real world. Even Bitcoin has a central government.
|
|
|
|
We can't force you to accept these axioms. We'll just assume
|
|
they're true for the rest of this document. This means we're
|
|
designing a new, self-governing network on top of the Internet.
|
|
|
|
## On digital republics
|
|
|
|
The English word *republic* is from the Latin *res publica* -
|
|
"public thing." A republic is a government run as a public
|
|
trust, without any single point of failure - person or
|
|
institution.
|
|
|
|
Every (real) democracy is a republic, but not every republic is a
|
|
democracy. The distribution of both formal and actual authority
|
|
within a republic need not be in any way uniform. (Arguably, it
|
|
never is.)
|
|
|
|
The design goal of a republic is effective, durable and stable
|
|
governance. Humans and servers are inherently fallible.
|
|
Therefore this goal cannot be achieved without what humans call
|
|
*pluralism* and programmers *redundancy*. Or in other words,
|
|
decentralized governance.
|
|
|
|
Both the old Internet of the '80s and the distributed social
|
|
network built on top of it - Usenet - were very much digital
|
|
republics. ICANN still thinks of itself as a republic, but to
|
|
some it looks more like a corporation. In previous decades,
|
|
influence over collective decisions was more about personal
|
|
reputation than corporate authority - the way IETF still works.
|
|
|
|
A republic needs a constitution - a set of formal processes that
|
|
guides and shapes the real questions of governance, which are
|
|
always informal.
|
|
|
|
The republic is in a healthy state if its actual power structures
|
|
match this constitution. The Soviet Union had a fine
|
|
constitution. Its actual authority structures had little to do
|
|
with its official structures.
|
|
|
|
Again, the digital republic is a machine - if it's not
|
|
well-engineered, it won't work. There are three categories of
|
|
engineering we have to get right: political, economic, social.
|
|
|
|
## Political engineering
|
|
|
|
Our ideal network is actually not designed to *be* a digital
|
|
republic. It's designed to *become* a digital republic.
|
|
|
|
The most basic principle of political engineering is that there
|
|
is no one true constitution; the constitution has to fit the
|
|
polity. And our polity cannot succeed without changing. And we
|
|
care what it ends up as, much more than how it gets there.
|
|
|
|
### On young networks
|
|
|
|
In a young, small network, digital freedom is irrelevant. There
|
|
is no structural conflict of interest between the government and
|
|
the users. Everyone in the network is a pioneer, and all
|
|
pioneers have the same goal: found the republic. Anyone who
|
|
stops believing in the network just leaves.
|
|
|
|
The young network is a high-trust society in two ways: trust
|
|
between users, and trust in government. The main purpose
|
|
of decentralization is to prevent conflict among the distrusting.
|
|
Decentralization is superfluous in a high-trust society.
|
|
|
|
A young network can't be decentralized *even if it wants to be*.
|
|
Consider the early days of Bitcoin. Somewhere between the
|
|
initial release and now, there's a point in time T such that
|
|
before but not after T, Satoshi himself could have rebooted the
|
|
blockchain.
|
|
|
|
Not even with a 51% attack - but *just with an email*. He could
|
|
have said: I screwed something up, here's a new genesis block.
|
|
And everyone would have switched to the new blockchain, at the
|
|
mere verbal whim of Emperor Satoshi.
|
|
|
|
When Bitcoin was young, it was a centralized network, even though
|
|
it had a decentralized constitution. In practice, Satoshi was
|
|
above the constitution. Even if he didn't use it, he had an
|
|
authority above cryptography.
|
|
|
|
### Political engineering in Bitcoin
|
|
|
|
There are two layers of sovereignty in Bitcoin. The highest
|
|
layer is the choice of blockchain itself - the rule that the
|
|
longest chain is best is completely informal. Or to put it
|
|
differently, it's the principle that makes Bitcoin Bitcoin and
|
|
everything else an altcoin. No math is involved here - just the
|
|
agreement of human beings. Or in other words, politics.
|
|
|
|
Even the cryptographic layer rests on informal foundations.
|
|
The 51% attack on Bitcoin is well-known; any coalition that can
|
|
construct one is sovereign. But no such coup has happened, or
|
|
will - why?
|
|
|
|
Because the coalition is plural. Since each coup supporter would
|
|
be acting against its own self-interest by damaging the
|
|
reputation of the currency as a whole, the coup requires
|
|
self-destructive folly from multiple serious actors. Suicidal
|
|
collusion is never a realistic risk - or if it is, nothing can
|
|
mitigate it.
|
|
|
|
Even if one miner controlled 51%, their incentive against an
|
|
attack would be enormous, because they would destroy the
|
|
blockchain they captured. On the other hand, not everyone
|
|
responds sensibly to incentives. The purpose of a republican
|
|
constitution is to eliminate single points of incentive failure.
|
|
|
|
Bitcoin is a stable, mature republic - but it is *not* secured
|
|
just by cryptography, but also by political engineering.
|
|
|
|
### Political engineering in Reddit
|
|
|
|
Compare to an unstable, mature non-republic: Reddit.
|
|
|
|
2015's Reddit civil war is a dead ringer for one past conflict:
|
|
the English Civil War. As Marx and Pareto agree, all major civic
|
|
conflict arises when a new social class develops a collective
|
|
sense of its right to govern. The danger is most acute when a
|
|
governed class senses that the governors do not live up to the
|
|
standards of the governed.
|
|
|
|
Much as the Puritans looked down on the Cavaliers as immoral,
|
|
atheistic fops, the Reddit moderators looked down on the Reddit
|
|
staff - or certain parts of it - as faceless corporate drones.
|
|
When you've attained real political status in a community,
|
|
through hard work and genuine talent, it's contemptible to let
|
|
yourself be governed by people without the basic skills to even
|
|
pass as competent, much less exceptional, in this community. As
|
|
Napoleon said: every regime is safe so long as it is ruled by its
|
|
most talented citizens. And if it's not, it isn't.
|
|
|
|
But technically, Reddit couldn't just have a French Revolution.
|
|
Reddit is an inherently centralized site. It looks like a bunch
|
|
of different places, but that's an illusion. It's actually one
|
|
big mainframe. The Reddit staff is stuck running this mainframe.
|
|
The users have a lot of social capital invested in it.
|
|
|
|
If there was a technical mechanism that let the users of Reddit,
|
|
collectively and coherently, fork Reddit and take ownership with
|
|
a Tennis Court Oath, they certainly would have done so long ago.
|
|
The result could only be a digital republic. But they can't, so
|
|
Reddit's future is unclear. Man may be born free, but mainframe
|
|
guest accounts certainly aren't born free.
|
|
|
|
### From monarchy to republic
|
|
|
|
In real-world history we see a curious pattern: not only are
|
|
republics fairly rare, but every successful republic (from Athens
|
|
to Rome to England) started out as a successful monarchy.
|
|
Perhaps this is also the right way to build a digital republic?
|
|
|
|
Another way to state the political engineering problem that our
|
|
new network has to solve: maximize the chance of producing a
|
|
mature digital republic. There are two failure cases: failure,
|
|
and a mature non-republic. We should prefer the former - "range
|
|
safety," as a rocket scientist would say.
|
|
|
|
Our conclusion is that a young network is a monarchy (whether
|
|
under a BDFL or a faceless corporation), whether it likes it or
|
|
not. But the network must be technically designed to *evolve*
|
|
into a mature republic.
|
|
|
|
And - most critically - the republican evolution *cannot* be
|
|
prevented by the monarchical admins. When the evolution has to
|
|
happen, the monarchy has every incentive to help it succeed. If
|
|
it chooses to interfere instead, it will just get run over.
|
|
|
|
Reddit couldn't have a revolution; its code wasn't designed for a
|
|
revolution. A new network can and should be designed for just
|
|
that. Revolution may not be the ideal way to give birth to a
|
|
republic, but it certainly works and it's better than nothing.
|
|
|
|
Thus what seems like an optimal political design: the ugly,
|
|
centralized, young larva that's designed to molt into a
|
|
beautiful, mature, decentralized butterfly. And once mature, the
|
|
larva must molt or die — not keep growing into a gigantic,
|
|
man-eating caterpillar of death.
|
|
|
|
## Economic engineering
|
|
|
|
Economically, a new network should bootstrap. It should be
|
|
designed to generate revenue that funds its own development.
|
|
Ideally, its operators accept no traditional investment at all.
|
|
|
|
A digital-token business is no novelty in the age of Bitcoin.
|
|
But a network address space is not at all the same thing as a
|
|
digital currency. When we look at current address spaces of
|
|
meaningful economic weight - DNS domains, IPv4 addresses, even
|
|
Twitter handles - we see not digital money, but digital *land*.
|
|
|
|
### On digital land
|
|
|
|
Digital land is very different from digital money. People mine
|
|
gold, but nobody mines land. Transactions in money are common,
|
|
fungible, and should involve minimal friction. Transactions in
|
|
land are rare, unique, and involve significant friction. And
|
|
most important, land has intrinsic utility; money does not.
|
|
|
|
For example, Bitcoin needs a blockchain to solve the double spend
|
|
problem. A blockchain is very expensive. If we consider mining
|
|
dilution as a cost, a Bitcoin transaction costs multiple dollars.
|
|
That cost is exacted as a dilution tax on all holders (arguably,
|
|
correct accounting in BTC uses a "normalized BTC" unit which is
|
|
the fraction of all BTC outstanding), but it remains a cost.
|
|
|
|
For certain values of "solved," the double spend problem is also
|
|
solved by a trusted escrow agent. For digital money, escrow is
|
|
not a workable general solution. For digital land, it may be.
|
|
Escrow is certainly orders of magnitude cheaper than a blockchain.
|
|
|
|
Digital land in a decentralized system still needs to be owned
|
|
cryptographically, like Bitcoin. But as with real property,
|
|
it doesn't need to be mathematically impossible to steal digital
|
|
property. It just needs to be realistically impractical. If we
|
|
can ensure that those with the power to steal lack the motive,
|
|
and those with the motive lack the power, our design works.
|
|
|
|
For digital land, a blockchain is an unnecessary expense. So
|
|
digital land has no mining. But from the Bitcoin purist's
|
|
perspective, any altcoin without mining is "100% premined" - ie,
|
|
probably a scam. Digital land is not digital currency, but it's
|
|
silly to argue over definitions.
|
|
|
|
### A moral theory of digital land
|
|
|
|
The libertarian philosophy of Murray Rothbard is the normative
|
|
belief system of Bitcoin. It's easy to explain digital land in
|
|
Rothbardian terms: ownership is on the homesteading principle.
|
|
|
|
Property in land, as anything, is owned by those who create it -
|
|
which in real land means enclosing and cultivating it. Digital
|
|
land is just the same, but creation is a simpler process - and
|
|
it never involves conquest and/or genocide of previous owners.
|
|
All this is precisely according to Dr. Rothbard.
|
|
|
|
Intuitively: if you didn't do any real work to create your
|
|
premined altcoin, it's a scam. If not, not. It's not necessary
|
|
to appeal to Rothbard to see why this makes sense.
|
|
|
|
### Economic dynamics
|
|
|
|
Any bootstrapping address space can define a metric which is the
|
|
fraction of namespace value recycled into development cost: the
|
|
erecycle rate*. In a sense, if the recycle rate is 100%, the
|
|
network does not leak economic energy.
|
|
|
|
(In a scam, this non-leaked economic energy non-leaks into the
|
|
scammer's pocket. In a non-scam, it goes back into the engine.
|
|
It's expensive to settle any new America; if that America has
|
|
positive general utility, its value when settled should subsidize
|
|
the cost of settling it. Or at least, a design that doesn't work
|
|
this way is like Newcomen's steam engine, not Watt's.)
|
|
|
|
One tradeoff against perfect recycling is the importance of
|
|
ownership decentralization. If you own an entire network because
|
|
you created it, you can increase the value of the whole address
|
|
space by giving blocks away. You may even increase the value of
|
|
your own position.
|
|
|
|
A monopolized network is not politically healthy. So its
|
|
economic value is lower. So — if the network is properly
|
|
designed and structured — it can be stably demonopolized. The
|
|
monopoly power achieved by combining large positions is smaller
|
|
than the reputation cost of remonopolization, so centrifugal
|
|
force dominates and the system stays decentralized.
|
|
|
|
Mining is one way to create initial demonopoly. But if it's not
|
|
actually necessary, mining has a recycle rate of zero. In a
|
|
blockchain network, mining is a necessary service and pays for
|
|
itself. In digital real estate, it would be a bad design.
|
|
|
|
The objective of demonopolization isn't necessarily a *fair*
|
|
distribution of real estate. Fairness is nice - but from an
|
|
engineering perspective, to create the incentive structure of a
|
|
true republic, all that's needed is nontrivial decentralization.
|
|
Not much is needed to maintain the stabilizing incentives.
|
|
|
|
## Regulatory engineering
|
|
|
|
There's another kind of "political engineering." Our new network
|
|
is a sort of second-level political entity; but it exists within
|
|
a first-level entity, the real government.
|
|
|
|
Minimizing bad interactions with the real government involves
|
|
three simple steps. First, don't look like you're breaking the
|
|
law. Second, don't break the law. Third, *really* don't break
|
|
the spirit of the law.
|
|
|
|
Fortunately, digital land (such as DNS domains or IPv4 blocks)
|
|
already exists and is largely unregulated. Or rather, it's
|
|
regulated perfectly well by standard property law.
|
|
|
|
This isn't just an accident of history. If DNS domains became a
|
|
useful way to launder money, or any kind of sink of financial
|
|
skulduggery, carders, pedobears, etc - the baleful eye of the
|
|
real government would rapidly fall on them.
|
|
|
|
It's incumbent on anyone creating a new network of any kind not
|
|
just to avoid using it *yourself* for criminal purposes, but to
|
|
design it so that *it's not useful* for criminal purposes. A
|
|
darknet is not a machine for producing digital freedom. It's the
|
|
opposite - an excuse for installing digital tyranny.
|
|
|
|
## Social engineering
|
|
|
|
Bringing people together is an easy problem for any social
|
|
network. The hard problem is keeping them apart. In other
|
|
words, the hard problem is *filtering*. Society is filtering.
|
|
|
|
A society without filters is a whirling, beige mess of atoms in a
|
|
blender. Beigeworld is an inhuman antisociety. A digital
|
|
republic is a garden; not only does a garden smell good, but
|
|
every flower smells good. An unfiltered network is a sewer. All
|
|
sewers have exactly the same smell.
|
|
|
|
There are four orthogonal classes of filtering: topic, community,
|
|
flavor and quality. Filtering should be orthogonal to content
|
|
type: the topic filter "sci.physics" can be a chatroom, a
|
|
preprint archive and a streaming video channel.
|
|
|
|
### Filtering: topic
|
|
|
|
Users themselves want to keep themselves apart in structured
|
|
ways. Topic filtering is the most basic. Imagine a Reddit or a
|
|
Usenet with only one group. It would consist only of noise.
|
|
|
|
For topic filtering, the ideal network has a single, organized
|
|
global topic tree (ontology). Call it half Usenet, half
|
|
Wikipedia and half the Dewey Decimal System.
|
|
|
|
### Filtering: community
|
|
|
|
Every topic deserves a community. But not every community is a
|
|
topic - a node in the ontology. To put it differently, not every
|
|
community should have a global name. The existence of small,
|
|
informal, private communities - tribes and microtribes - is
|
|
essential to a healthy network.
|
|
|
|
The most inhuman form of community filtering is the form in which
|
|
"communities" are inferred algorithmically from an unstructured
|
|
social graph on a social server. A community is a tribe, not a
|
|
proximity cluster. Humans are a tribal species and have
|
|
exquisite instincts for interactions in medium-sized groups.
|
|
|
|
### Filtering: flavor
|
|
|
|
Flavor filtering is the only major filtering class that's poorly
|
|
developed in presently deployed systems.
|
|
|
|
Suppose you're building an online grocery store. Suppose one
|
|
feature of your store is a profile setting where users can mark
|
|
that they're vegetarians.
|
|
|
|
There is no use in asking vegetarians to shop for meat. At best,
|
|
you're trolling them; at worst, you're boring them. A cooking
|
|
site should not show them recipes for rack of lamb. Etc.
|
|
|
|
More broadly, many forms of discourse have vibrant flavors which
|
|
other users are inherently uninterested in tasting. Like topics,
|
|
these flavors naturally form trees - some users may naturally
|
|
block all sexual content, others just a subset.
|
|
|
|
But flavors are not topics. Topic can imply flavor - the bondage
|
|
board will have bondage-flavored content. Not all communities
|
|
are topical. Not all all topical communities stick to the point
|
|
in every single communication.
|
|
|
|
A key component of flavor-oriented filtering is the principle
|
|
that flavor is marked by the content author, and enforced by
|
|
social convention in the community. A well-run community - and
|
|
not all communities will be well-run - enforces flavor marking
|
|
even among the locally dominant majority.
|
|
|
|
Anyone reading this has been subject to speech codes, of one sort
|
|
or another, since they were old enough to talk. There's a reason
|
|
for this: blasphemy and/or heresy is disruptive and antisocial,
|
|
absolutely regardless of its actual intellectual merit.
|
|
|
|
If we have a technical way to filter out blasphemy, we don't need
|
|
to suppress it with coercive force. Imagine a world in which,
|
|
not just in theory but also in practice, you could say anything
|
|
you wanted - so long as you marked it as what it was.
|
|
|
|
### Filtering: quality
|
|
|
|
All other filtering problems are unimportant next to quality.
|
|
Any successful digital republic must be in some sense a successor
|
|
of Usenet, whose defeat by the barbarians is a matter of history.
|
|
Alas, no one really knows how to do decentralized quality
|
|
filtering. (Even centralized filtering doesn't work well.)
|
|
|
|
Fortunately, a young network is inherently high-quality.
|
|
Low-quality content is parasitic. It develops only as a network
|
|
matures. There's plenty of time to work on the outer walls while
|
|
the network boots up.
|
|
|
|
And we can state one social-engineering goal which is not
|
|
*sufficient* for barbarian resistance, but perhaps almost
|
|
*necessary*. This is *expansion resistance*: the difficulty of
|
|
creating a new identity.
|
|
|
|
If expansion resistance is zero, anyone can create infinite
|
|
numbers of identities; Sybil attacks become trivial. Expansion
|
|
resistance is negligible in email; spam filtering works, kind of;
|
|
it can save SMTP, it certainly couldn't *create* SMTP. Email has
|
|
a lot in common with 14th-century Constantinople.
|
|
|
|
Metafilter (which anyone can join for $5) has solid expansion
|
|
resistance; it may not be perfect, but it's certainly spamless.
|
|
And the grand champion is certainly the '80s Arpanet, where where
|
|
creating an identity involved applying to a university or getting
|
|
a tech job - effectively, infinite expansion resistance.
|
|
|
|
Imagine a genuinely abuse-free global, decentralized network,
|
|
where no one had ever heard of a firewall. Usenet was a fragile
|
|
flower that could only exist under this glass bell. We can't
|
|
go back to the Arpanet, but we have to understand why it worked.
|
|
|
|
Broadly, disposable identities and sockpuppets are the enemy of
|
|
Internet civilization. The principle of one identity per person,
|
|
persona or corporation is an absolute principle of netiquette.
|
|
Genuine multiple personas exist - it's one thing to split your
|
|
own identity between person and persona, name and *nom de plume*
|
|
or *nom de drag* - but they're rare, and an easy exception.
|
|
|
|
One of the most praised texts in 20th-century political science
|
|
is s James Scott's _Seeing Like A State_. Scott points out that
|
|
successful governments encourage social structures which are
|
|
structurally governable, like a forester planting rows of trees
|
|
in straight lines. People today have names like "Carter" because
|
|
medieval English barons made their peasants take surnames, just
|
|
so their tax databases would have valid primary keys.
|
|
|
|
A naive libertarian might call this a bad thing. Simplicity is
|
|
not tyranny; simple government is good government, which is the
|
|
opposite of tyranny. The simpler its task, the less energy the
|
|
government must exert to achieve the same output. Anarchy and
|
|
tyranny are cousins; so are liberty and order.
|
|
|
|
# Conclusion
|
|
|
|
Goals and ideals are different things. An ideal is something you
|
|
want. A goal is an ideal, plus a realistic plan to get it.
|
|
Goals are more interesting than ideals, don't you think?
|
|
|
|
Goals and features are also different things. What are the
|
|
features of a network that attempts to achieve these design
|
|
goals? In the next installment, we'll look at how our own
|
|
network — [Urbit](http://urbit.org) — measures up to these
|
|
yardsticks.
|